Interest rate










An interest rate is the amount of interest due per period, as a proportion of the amount lent, deposited or borrowed (called the principal sum). The total interest on an amount lent or borrowed depends on the principal sum, the interest rate, the compounding frequency, and the length of time over which it is lent, deposited or borrowed.


It is defined as the proportion of an amount loaned which a lender charges as interest to the borrower, normally expressed as an annual percentage.[1] It is the rate a bank or other lender charges to borrow its money, or the rate a bank pays its savers for keeping money in an account.[2]


Annual interest rate is the rate over a period of one year. Other interest rates apply over different periods, such as a month or a day, but they are usually annualised.




Contents





  • 1 Influencing factors


  • 2 Example


  • 3 Related terms


  • 4 Monetary policy


  • 5 History


  • 6 Reasons for changes


  • 7 Non-market-based theories


  • 8 Real vs nominal


  • 9 Market rates

    • 9.1 Inflationary expectations


    • 9.2 Risk


    • 9.3 Liquidity preference


    • 9.4 A market model


    • 9.5 Spread



  • 10 In macroeconomics

    • 10.1 Elasticity of substitution


    • 10.2 Output and unemployment


    • 10.3 Open market operations in the United States


    • 10.4 Money and inflation



  • 11 Impact on savings and pensions


  • 12 Mathematical note


  • 13 Zero rate policy


  • 14 Negative nominal rates

    • 14.1 On central bank reserves

      • 14.1.1 Theory


      • 14.1.2 Practice



    • 14.2 On government bond yields


    • 14.3 On corporate bond yields



  • 15 See also


  • 16 Notes


  • 17 References




Influencing factors


Interest rates vary according to:


  • the government's directives to the central bank to accomplish the government's goals

  • the currency of the principal sum lent or borrowed

  • the term to maturity of the investment

  • the perceived default probability of the borrower

  • supply and demand in the market

as well as other factors.



Example


A company borrows capital from a bank to buy assets for its business. In return, the bank charges the company interest. (The lender might also require rights over the new assets as collateral.)



Related terms


Base rate usually refers to the annualized rate offered on overnight deposits by the central bank or other monetary authority.[citation needed]


Annual percentage rate (APR) and effective annual rate or annual equivalent rate (AER) are used to help consumers compare products with different payment structures on a common basis.


A discount rate is applied to calculate present value.


For an interest-bearing security, coupon rate is the ratio of the annual coupon amount (the coupon paid per year) per unit of par value, whereas current yield is the ratio of the annual coupon divided by its current market price. Yield to maturity is a bond's expected internal rate of return, assuming it will be held to maturity, that is, the discount rate which equates all remaining cash flows to the investor (all remaining coupons and repayment of the par value at maturity) with the current market price.



Monetary policy


Interest rate targets are a vital tool of monetary policy and are taken into account when dealing with variables like investment, inflation, and unemployment. The central banks of countries generally tend to reduce interest rates when they wish to increase investment and consumption in the country's economy. However, a low interest rate as a macro-economic policy can be risky and may lead to the creation of an economic bubble, in which large amounts of investments are poured into the real-estate market and stock market. In developed economies, interest-rate adjustments are thus made to keep inflation within a target range for the health of economic activities or cap the interest rate concurrently with economic growth to safeguard economic momentum.[3][4][5][6][7]



History




Germany experienced deposit interest rates from 14% in 1969 down to almost 2% in 2003


In the past two centuries, interest rates have been variously set either by national governments or central banks. For example, the Federal Reserve federal funds rate in the United States has varied between about 0.25% to 19% from 1954 to 2008, while the Bank of England base rate varied between 0.5% and 15% from 1989 to 2009,[8][9] and Germany experienced rates close to 90% in the 1920s down to about 2% in the 2000s.[10][11] During an attempt to tackle spiraling hyperinflation in 2007, the Central Bank of Zimbabwe increased interest rates for borrowing to 800%.[12]


The interest rates on prime credits in the late 1970s and early 1980s were far higher than had been recorded – higher than previous US peaks since 1800, than British peaks since 1700, or than Dutch peaks since 1600; "since modern capital markets came into existence, there have never been such high long-term rates" as in this period.[13]


Possibly before modern capital markets, there have been some accounts that savings deposits could achieve an annual return of at least 25% and up to as high as 50%. (William Ellis and Richard Dawes, "Lessons on the Phenomenon of Industrial Life... ", 1857, p III–IV)



Reasons for changes



  • Political short-term gain: Lowering interest rates can give the economy a short-run boost. Under normal conditions, most economists think a cut in interest rates will only give a short term gain in economic activity that will soon be offset by inflation. The quick boost can influence elections. Most economists advocate independent central banks to limit the influence of politics on interest rates.


  • Deferred consumption: When money is loaned the lender delays spending the money on consumption goods. Since according to time preference theory people prefer goods now to goods later, in a free market there will be a positive interest rate.


  • Inflationary expectations: Most economies generally exhibit inflation, meaning a given amount of money buys fewer goods in the future than it will now. The borrower needs to compensate the lender for this.


  • Alternative investments: The lender has a choice between using his money in different investments. If he chooses one, he forgoes the returns from all the others. Different investments effectively compete for funds.


  • Risks of investment: There is always a risk that the borrower will go bankrupt, abscond, die, or otherwise default on the loan. This means that a lender generally charges a risk premium to ensure that, across his investments, he is compensated for those that fail.


  • Liquidity preference: People prefer to have their resources available in a form that can immediately be exchanged, rather than a form that takes time to realize.


  • Taxes: Because some of the gains from interest may be subject to taxes, the lender may insist on a higher rate to make up for this loss.


  • Banks: Banks can tend to change the interest rate to either slow down or speed up economy growth. This involves either raising interest rates to slow the economy down, or lowering interest rates to promote economic growth.[14]


  • Economy: Interest rates can fluctuate according to the status of the economy. It will generally be found that if the economy is strong then the interest rates will be high, if the economy is weak the interest rates will be low.


Non-market-based theories


Some economists like Karl Marx argue that interest rates are not actually set purely by market competition. Rather they argue that interest rates are ultimately set in line with social customs and legal institutions. Karl Marx writes:


"Customs, juristic tradition, etc., have as much to do with determining the average rate of interest as competition itself, in so far as it exists not merely as an average, but rather as actual magnitude. In many law disputes, where interest has to be calculated, an average rate of interest has to be assumed as the legal rate. If we inquire further as to why the limits of a mean rate of interest cannot be deduced from general laws, we find the answer lies simply in the nature of interest."[15]



Real vs nominal




The nominal interest rate is the rate of interest with no adjustment for inflation.


For example, suppose someone deposits $100 with a bank for 1 year, and they receive interest of $10 (before tax), so at the end of the year, their balance is $110 (before tax). In this case, regardless of the rate of inflation, the nominal interest rate is 10% per annum (before tax).


The real interest rate measures the growth in real value of the loan plus interest, taking inflation into account. The repayment of principal plus interest is measured in real terms compared against the buying power of the amount at the time it was borrowed, lent, deposited or invested.


If inflation is 10%, then the $110 in the account at the end of the year has the same purchasing power (that is, buys the same amount) as the $100 had a year ago. The real interest rate is zero in this case.


The real interest rate is given by the Fisher equation:


r=1+i1+p−1displaystyle r=frac 1+i1+p-1,!r=frac 1+i1+p-1,!

where p is the inflation rate.
For low rates and short periods, the linear approximation applies:


r≈i−pdisplaystyle rapprox i-p,!rapprox i-p,!

The Fisher equation applies both ex ante and ex post. Ex ante, the rates are projected rates, whereas ex post, the rates are historical.



Market rates


There is a market for investments, including the money market, bond market, stock market, and currency market as well as retail banking.


Interest rates reflect:


  • The risk-free cost of capital

  • Expected inflation

  • Risk premium

  • Transaction costs


Inflationary expectations


According to the theory of rational expectations, borrowers and lenders form an expectation of inflation in the future. The acceptable nominal interest rate at which they are willing and able to borrow or lend includes the real interest rate they require to receive, or are willing and able to pay, plus the rate of inflation they expect.



Risk


The level of risk in investments is taken into consideration. Riskier investments such as shares and junk bonds are normally expected to deliver higher returns than safer ones like government bonds.


The additional return above the risk-free nominal interest rate which is expected from a risky investment is the risk premium. The risk premium an investor requires on an investment depends on the risk preferences of the investor. Evidence suggests that most lenders are risk-averse.[16]


A maturity risk premium applied to a longer-term investment reflects a higher perceived risk of default.



Liquidity preference


Most investors prefer their money to be in cash than in less fungible investments. Cash is on hand to be spent immediately if the need arises, but some investments require time or effort to transfer into spendable form. This is known as liquidity preference. A 1-year loan, for instance, is very liquid compared to a 10-year loan. A 10-year US Treasury bond, however, is liquid because it can easily be sold on the market.



A market model


A basic interest rate pricing model for an asset


in=ir+pe+rp+lpdisplaystyle i_n=i_r+p_e+rp+lp,!i_n=i_r+p_e+rp+lp,!

Assuming perfect information, pe is the same for all participants in the market, and this is identical to:


in=in∗+rp+lpdisplaystyle i_n=i_n^*+rp+lp,!i_n=i_n^*+rp+lp,!

where



in is the nominal interest rate on a given investment


ir is the risk-free return to capital


i*n = the nominal interest rate on a short-term risk-free liquid bond (such as U.S. Treasury Bills).


rp = a risk premium reflecting the length of the investment and the likelihood the borrower will default


lp = liquidity premium (reflecting the perceived difficulty of converting the asset into money and thus into goods).


Spread


The spread of interest rates is the lending rate minus the deposit rate.[17] This spread covers operating costs for banks providing loans and deposits. A negative spread is where a deposit rate is higher than the lending rate.[18]



In macroeconomics



Elasticity of substitution


The elasticity of substitution (full name is the marginal rate of substitution of the relative allocation) affects the real interest rate. The larger the magnitude of the elasticity of substitution, the more the exchange, and the lower the real interest rate.



Output and unemployment


Higher interest rates increase the cost of borrowing which can reduce investment and output and increase unemployment. Expanding businesses, especially entrepreneurs tend to be net debtors. However, the Austrian School of Economics sees higher rates as leading to greater investment in order to earn the interest to pay its creditors. Higher rates encourage more saving and reduce inflation.



Open market operations in the United States




The effective federal funds rate in the US charted over more than half a century


The Federal Reserve (often referred to as 'The Fed') implements monetary policy largely by targeting the federal funds rate. This is the rate that banks charge each other for overnight loans of federal funds, which are the reserves held by banks at the Fed.
Open market operations are one tool within monetary policy implemented by the Federal Reserve to steer short-term interest rates using the power to buy and sell treasury securities.



Money and inflation


Loans, bonds, and shares have some of the characteristics of money and are included in the broad money supply.


By setting i*n, the government institution can affect the markets to alter the total of loans, bonds and shares issued. Generally speaking, a higher real interest rate reduces the broad money supply.


Through the quantity theory of money, increases in the money supply lead to inflation.



Impact on savings and pensions


Financial economists such as World Pensions Council (WPC) researchers have argued that durably low interest rates in most G20 countries will have an adverse impact on the funding positions of pension funds as “without returns that outstrip inflation, pension investors face the real value of their savings declining rather than ratcheting up over the next few years” [19]


From 1982 until 2012, most Western economies experienced a period of low inflation combined with relatively high returns on investments across all asset classes including government bonds. This brought a certain sense of complacency amongst some pension actuarial consultants and regulators, making it seem reasonable to use optimistic economic assumptions to calculate the present value of future pension liabilities.


This potentially long-lasting collapse in returns on government bonds is taking place against the backdrop of a protracted fall in returns for other core-assets such as blue chip stocks, and, more importantly, a silent demographic shock. Factoring in the corresponding "longevity risk", pension premiums could be raised significantly while disposable incomes stagnate and employees work longer years before retiring.[19]



Mathematical note


Because interest and inflation are generally given as percentage increases, the formulae above are (linear) approximations.


For instance,


in=ir+pedisplaystyle i_n=i_r+p_e,!i_n=i_r+p_e,!

is only approximate. In reality, the relationship is


(1+in)=(1+ir)(1+pe)displaystyle (1+i_n)=(1+i_r)(1+p_e),!(1+i_n)=(1+i_r)(1+p_e),!

so


ir=1+in1+pe−1displaystyle i_r=frac 1+i_n1+p_e-1,!i_r=frac 1+i_n1+p_e-1,!

The two approximations, eliminating higher order terms, are:


(1+x)(1+y)=1+x+y+xy≈1+x+y11+x=1−x+x2−x3+⋯≈1−xdisplaystyle beginaligned(1+x)(1+y)&=1+x+y+xy&&approx 1+x+y\frac 11+x&=1-x+x^2-x^3+cdots &&approx 1-xendalignedbeginaligned(1+x)(1+y)&=1+x+y+xy&&approx 1+x+y\frac 11+x&=1-x+x^2-x^3+cdots &&approx 1-xendaligned

The formulae in this article are exact if logarithmic units are used for relative changes, or equivalently if logarithms of indices are used in place of rates, and hold even for large relative changes. Most elegantly, if the natural logarithm is used, yielding the neper[citation needed] as logarithmic units, scaling by 100 to obtain the centineper yields units that are infinitesimally equal to percentage change (hence approximately equal for small values), and for which the linear equations hold for all values.



Zero rate policy



A so-called "zero interest-rate policy" (ZIRP) is a very low—near-zero—central bank target interest rate. At this zero lower bound the central bank faces difficulties with conventional monetary policy, because it is generally believed that market interest rates cannot realistically be pushed down into negative territory.



Negative nominal rates


Nominal interest rates are normally positive, but not always. In contrast, real interest rates can be negative, when nominal interest rates are below inflation. When this is done via government policy (for example, via reserve requirements), this is deemed financial repression, and was practiced by countries such as the United States and United Kingdom following World War II (from 1945) until the late 1970s or early 1980s (during and following the Post–World War II economic expansion).[20][21] In the late 1970s, United States Treasury securities with negative real interest rates were deemed certificates of confiscation.[22]



On central bank reserves



A so-called "negative interest rate policy" (NIRP) is a negative (below zero) central bank target interest rate.



Theory


Given the alternative of holding cash, and thus earning 0%, rather than lending it out, profit-seeking lenders will not lend below 0%, as that will guarantee a loss, and a bank offering a negative deposit rate will find few takers, as savers will instead hold cash.[23]


Negative interest rates have been proposed in the past, notably in the late 19th century by Silvio Gesell.[24] A negative interest rate can be described (as by Gesell) as a "tax on holding money"; he proposed it as the Freigeld (free money) component of his Freiwirtschaft (free economy) system. To prevent people from holding cash (and thus earning 0%), Gesell suggested issuing money for a limited duration, after which it must be exchanged for new bills; attempts to hold money thus result in it expiring and becoming worthless. Along similar lines, John Maynard Keynes approvingly cited the idea of a carrying tax on money,[24] (1936, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money) but dismissed it due to administrative difficulties.[25] More recently, a carry tax on currency was proposed by a Federal Reserve employee (Marvin Goodfriend) in 1999, to be implemented via magnetic strips on bills, deducting the carry tax upon deposit, the tax being based on how long the bill had been held.[25]


It has been proposed that a negative interest rate can in principle be levied on existing paper currency via a serial number lottery, such as randomly choosing a number 0 through 9 and declaring that notes whose serial number end in that digit are worthless, yielding an average 10% loss of paper cash holdings to hoarders; a drawn two-digit number could match the last two digits on the note for a 1% loss. This was proposed by an anonymous student of Greg Mankiw,[24] though more as a thought experiment than a genuine proposal.[26]


A much simpler method to achieve negative real interest rates and provide a disincentive to holding cash, is for governments to encourage mildly inflationary monetary policy; indeed, this is what Keynes recommended back in 1936.



Practice


Both the European Central Bank starting in 2014 and the Bank of Japan starting in early 2016 pursued the policy on top of their earlier and continuing quantitative easing policies. The latter's policy was said at its inception to be trying to 'change Japan’s “deflationary mindset.”' In 2016 Sweden, Denmark and Switzerland—not directly participants in the Euro currency zone—also had NIRPs in place.[27]


Countries such as Sweden and Denmark have set negative interest on reserves—that is to say, they have charged interest on reserves.[28][29][30][31]


In July 2009, Sweden's central bank, the Riksbank, set its policy repo rate, the interest rate on its one-week deposit facility, at 0.25%, at the same time as setting its overnight deposit rate at −0.25%.[32] The existence of the negative overnight deposit rate was a technical consequence of the fact that overnight deposit rates are generally set at 0.5% below or 0.75% below the policy rate.[32][33] This is not technically an example of "negative interest on excess reserves," because Sweden does not have a reserve requirement,[34] but imposing a reserve interest rate without reserve requirements imposes an implied reserve requirement of zero. The Riksbank studied the impact of these changes and stated in a commentary report[35] that they led to no disruptions in Swedish financial markets.


US Federal Reserve called a historic end to quantitative easing in September 2017 and recently raised its benchmark short-term interest rate by a quarter percentage point and signaled that two more hikes are likely this year. The decision moves the funds’ rate target to a range of 1.75% to 2%, from near zero in 2016.[36]



On government bond yields


During the European debt crisis, government bonds of some countries (Switzerland, Denmark, Germany, Finland, the Netherlands and Austria) have been sold at negative yields. Suggested explanations include desire for safety and protection against the eurozone breaking up (in which case some eurozone countries might redenominate their debt into a stronger currency).[37]



On corporate bond yields


For practical purposes, investors and academics typically view the yields on government or quasi-government bonds guaranteed by a small number of the most creditworthy governments (UK, USA, Switzerland, EU, Japan) to effectively have negligible default risk. As financial theory would predict, investors and academics typically do not view non-government guaranteed corporate bonds in the same way. Most credit analysts value them at a spread to similar government bonds with similar duration, geographic exposure, and currency exposure. Through 2018 there have only been a few of these corporate bonds that have traded at negative nominal interest rates.
The most notable example of this was Nestle, some of whose AAA-rated bonds traded at negative nominal interest rate in 2015. However, some academics and investors believe this may have been influenced by volatility in the currency market during this period.



See also


  • List of countries by central bank interest rates

  • Macroeconomics

  • Rate of return

  • Short-rate model


Notes




  1. ^ "interest rate - Definition of interest rate in English by Oxford Dictionaries". Oxford Dictionaries - English. Retrieved 8 January 2018..mw-parser-output cite.citationfont-style:inherit.mw-parser-output qquotes:"""""""'""'".mw-parser-output code.cs1-codecolor:inherit;background:inherit;border:inherit;padding:inherit.mw-parser-output .cs1-lock-free abackground:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/6/65/Lock-green.svg/9px-Lock-green.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center.mw-parser-output .cs1-lock-limited a,.mw-parser-output .cs1-lock-registration abackground:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/d/d6/Lock-gray-alt-2.svg/9px-Lock-gray-alt-2.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center.mw-parser-output .cs1-lock-subscription abackground:url("//upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/a/aa/Lock-red-alt-2.svg/9px-Lock-red-alt-2.svg.png")no-repeat;background-position:right .1em center.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registrationcolor:#555.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription span,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration spanborder-bottom:1px dotted;cursor:help.mw-parser-output .cs1-hidden-errordisplay:none;font-size:100%.mw-parser-output .cs1-visible-errorfont-size:100%.mw-parser-output .cs1-subscription,.mw-parser-output .cs1-registration,.mw-parser-output .cs1-formatfont-size:95%.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-left,.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-wl-leftpadding-left:0.2em.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-right,.mw-parser-output .cs1-kern-wl-rightpadding-right:0.2em


  2. ^ "interest rate Meaning in the Cambridge English Dictionary". Dictionary.cambridge.org. Retrieved 8 January 2018.


  3. ^ "INSIGHT-Mild inflation, low interest rates could help economy". Reuters. 2 August 2011.


  4. ^ Sepehri, Ardeshir; Moshiri, Saeed (2004). "Inflation‐Growth Profiles Across Countries: Evidence from Developing and Developed Countries". International Review of Applied Economics. 18 (2): 191–207. doi:10.1080/0269217042000186679.


  5. ^ "Inflation : Finding the right balance" (PDF). Imf.org. Retrieved 8 January 2018.


  6. ^ "Finance & Development, June 2003 - Contents". Finance and Development – F&D.


  7. ^ "Finance & Development, March 2010 – Back to Basics". Finance and Development – F&D.


  8. ^ moneyextra.com Interest Rate History Archived 2008-10-16 at the Wayback Machine.. Retrieved 2008-10-27


  9. ^ "UK interest rates lowered to 0.5%". BBC News. 5 March 2009.


  10. ^ (Homer, Sylla & Sylla 1996, p. 509)


  11. ^ Bundesbank. BBK – Statistics – Time series database Archived 2009-02-12 at the Wayback Machine.. Retrieved 2008-10-27


  12. ^ worldeconomies.co.uk Zimbabwe currency revised to help inflation Archived 2009-02-11 at the Wayback Machine.


  13. ^ (Homer, Sylla & Sylla 1996, p. 1)


  14. ^ Commonwealth Bank Why do Interest Rates Change? Archived 2014-02-26 at the Wayback Machine.


  15. ^ Marx, Karl. https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1894-c3/ch22.htm. Missing or empty |title= (help)


  16. ^ Benchimol, J., 2014. Risk aversion in the Eurozone, Research in Economics, vol. 68, issue 1, pp. 39–56.


  17. ^ Interest rate spread (lending rate minus deposit rate, %) from World Bank. 2012


  18. ^ Negative Spread Law & Legal Definition, retrieved January 2013


  19. ^ ab M. Nicolas J. Firzli quoted in Sinead Cruise (4 August 2012). "'Zero Return World Squeezes Retirement Plans'". Reuters with CNBC. . Retrieved 5 Aug 2012.


  20. ^ William H. Gross. "The Caine Mutiny Part 2 – PIMCO". Pacific Investment Management Company LLC.


  21. ^ "Financial Repression Redux (Reinhart, Kirkegaard, Sbrancia June 2011)" (PDF). Imf.org. Retrieved 8 January 2018.


  22. ^ Norris, Floyd (28 October 2010). "U.S. Bonds That Could Return Less Than Their Price". The New York Times.


  23. ^ Buiter, Willem (7 May 2009). "Negative interest rates: when are they coming to a central bank near you?". Financial Times blog.


  24. ^ abc Mankiw, N. Gregory (18 April 2009). "It May Be Time for the Fed to Go Negative". The New York Times.


  25. ^ ab McCullagh, Declan (27 October 1999). "Cash and the 'Carry Tax'". WIRED. Retrieved 2011-12-21.


  26. ^

    See follow-up blog posts for discussion: "Observations on Negative Interest Rates", 19 April 2009;
    "More on Negative Interest Rates", 22 April 2009; "More on Negative Interest Rates", 7 May 2009, all in Greg Mankiw's Blog: Random Observations for Students of Economics



  27. ^ Nakamichi, Takashi, Megumi Fujikawa and Eleanor Warnock, "Bank of Japan Introduces Negative Interest Rates" (possibly subscription-only), Wall Street Journal, January 29, 2016. Retrieved 2016-01-29.


  28. ^ Goodhart, C.A.E. (January 2013). "The Potential Instruments of Monetary Policy" (PDF). Financial Markets Group Paper (Special Paper 219). London School of Economics. 9–10. ISSN 1359-9151. Retrieved 13 April 2013.


  29. ^ Blinder, Alan S. (February 2012). "Revisiting Monetary Policy in a Low-Inflation and Low-Utilization Environment". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 44 (Supplement s1): 141–146. doi:10.1111/j.1538-4616.2011.00481.x. Retrieved 13 April 2013.


  30. ^ Thoma, Mark (August 27, 2012). "Would Lowering the Interest Rate on Excess Reserves Stimulate the Economy?". Economist's View. Retrieved 13 April 2013.


  31. ^ Parameswaran, Ashwin. "On The Folly of Inflation Targeting In A World Of Interest Bearing Money". Macroeconomic Resilience. Retrieved 13 April 2013.


  32. ^ ab "Repo rate table". Sveriges Riksbank. Retrieved 21 August 2013.


  33. ^ Ward, Andrew; Oakley, David (27 August 2009). "Bankers watch as Sweden goes negative". Financial Times. London.


  34. ^ Gray, Simon (February 2011). "Central Bank Balances and Reserve Requirements" (PDF). International Monetary Fund. Retrieved 5 October 2013.


  35. ^ Beechey, Meredith; Elmér, Heidi (30 September 2009). "The lower limit of the Riksbank's repo rate" (PDF). Sveriges Riksbank. Retrieved 21 August 2013.


  36. ^ "Global debt bomb ticking: GCC on the brink of a economic meltdown". ameinfo.com. Retrieved 2018-06-28.


  37. ^ Wigglesworth, Robin (18 July 2012). "Schatz yields turn negative for first time". Financial Times. London.




References



  • Homer, Sidney; Sylla, Richard Eugene; Sylla, Richard (1996). A History of Interest Rates. Rutgers University Press. ISBN 978-0-8135-2288-3. Retrieved 2008-10-27.








這個網誌中的熱門文章

How to read a connectionString WITH PROVIDER in .NET Core?

In R, how to develop a multiplot heatmap.2 figure showing key labels successfully

Museum of Modern and Contemporary Art of Trento and Rovereto